Thursday, January 30, 2020
A Book Report on ââ¬ÅHeatââ¬Â By Mike Lupika Essay Example for Free
A Book Report on ââ¬Å"Heatâ⬠By Mike Lupika Essay Sportswriter named Mike Lupika intelligently wrote a piece of story that proves life is still beautiful despite the heartbreaks and difficulties. The author also portrays a story that illuminates the truth that a personââ¬â¢s talent is special and must be developed by the one who was gifted as such. The social behavior displayed in the book is very degrading that some of the male characters in the book including their adult friends lied to the authorities (ââ¬Å"Heatâ⬠). However, the interesting and notable parts of the fiction are those that mentioned fast food like Mc Donald and those drink and clothing brands that were mentioned in the book. According to Common Sense Media Website, the book entitled ââ¬Å"Heatâ⬠has 220 pages and published by Penguin Putnam, Incorporated (ââ¬Å"Heatâ⬠). The book is also published last April 16, 2006 and its genre is fiction about sports (ââ¬Å"Heatâ⬠). There are many things that can be learned in the book like surviving in a difficult life, ethical standards like honesty, and developing a gift or talent that only a few lucky people can have in this world. Moreover, the book entitled ââ¬Å"Heatâ⬠is a story about a boy who is so talented in the field of baseball sports. The story of Michael who is a 12 year-old pitcher tells about being poor and orphaned but with positive attitude in life. The story revolves around the hopes of Michaelââ¬â¢s father that his son could play with the Little League World Series. Michaelââ¬â¢s difficulties worsened when he was accused by a player and a rival coach that the disclosure of his age was fabricated (ââ¬Å"Heatâ⬠). As a result, Michael was suspended from playing baseball after it was divulged and alleged that he was older that he mentioned in his profile as a player. However, Michael was able to face all these problems positively by being cheerful and well-adjusted. Works Cited ââ¬Å"Heatâ⬠. 2008. Common Sense Media Website. 8 September 2008 http://www. commonsensemedia. org/book-reviews/Heat. html
Wednesday, January 22, 2020
Legalizing Abortion and Back-alley Abortionists :: Argumentative Persuasive Topics
Legalizing Abortion and Back-alley Abortionists à à à à The head of one of the major pro-choice/pro-abortion organizations in the U.S. has said: "In 1972 there were 1,000,000 illegal abortions and 5,000 to 10,000 women died from them." The data would indicate that legalized abortion is a godsend for women. This essay will examine the truth or falsity of the above quote in all of its complexity. à True? Or False? No one knows. For the obvious reason that illegal abortions have never been reported. There are no statistics, no numbers anywhere to report. Therefore, if anyone tells you that there were X numbers of illegal abortions somewhere in a certain time, they are guessing. The pro-abortion leader may guess 1,000,000. The pro-life spokesman may guess 100,000, but both are guessing. à There is only one reported figure that can lead us to some degree of accurate estimate of the numbers of illegal abortions and that is the number of women who died from illegal abortions. Many nations report only one figure for women who die, lumping together women's deaths from spontaneous abortion (miscarriage), legally induced abortion and illegally induced abortion. Such statistics are no help. The United States, since the 1940s, has reported such deaths separately, so we know the number of deaths from illegal abortions. Good! Now if we knew how many illegal abortions it took to cause one death, we could easily calculate the total number of illegal abortions. The problem is, no one has the slightest idea how many it took, and so we're back to where we started from. à How many women died? The chart used on the floor of the US Senate during the tumultuous debate on abortion in 1981 was compiled from official U.S. statistics and was not challenged by the pro-abortion forces. It shows that after Penicillin became available to control infections, the number of deaths stabilized during the 1950s at about 250/year. e.g. 1956 = 250. Note that by 1966, with abortion still illegal in all states, the number of deaths had dropped steadily to half that number - 120, because of new and better antibiotics, better surgery and the establishment of intensive care units in hospitals. This was in the face of a rising population. Between 1967 and 1970 sixteen states legalized abortion. In most it was limited, only for rape, incest and severe fetal handicap (life of mother was legal in all states).
Tuesday, January 14, 2020
Liberal Theory Essay
This memo outlines the liberal approach to theorizing international relations. Like realism, institutionalism, or non-rational approaches, it is a name given to a family of related theories of international relations. Here it will not be used, as many use it in international relations, to designate theories that stress the importance of international institutions. Nor to designate theories that stress the importance of universal, altruistic or utopian values of a liberal sort, such as human rights or democracy. Nor to designate theories favored by left-wing (ââ¬Å"liberalâ⬠) political parties or policies in the US. Instead, it is a theory that stresses the role of the varied social interests and values of states, and their relevance for world politics. Liberals argue that the universal condition of world politics is globalization. States are, and always have been, embedded in a domestic and transnational society, which creates incentives for economic, social and cultural interaction across borders. State policy may facilitate or block such interactions. Some domestic groups may benefit from or be harmed by such policies, and they pressure government accordingly for policies that facilitate realization of their goals. These social pressures, transmitted through domestic political institutions, define ââ¬Å"state preferencesâ⬠ââ¬âthat is, the set of substantive social purposes that motivate foreign policy. State preferences give governments an underlying stake in the international issues they face. Since the domestic and transnational social context in which states are embedded varies greatly across space and time, so do state preferences. Without such social concerns that transcend state borders, states would have no rational incentive to engage in world politics at all, but would simply devote their resources to an autarkic and isolated existence. To motivate conflict, cooperation, or any other costly foreign policy action, states must possess sufficiently intense state preferences. The resulting globalization-induced variation in social demands, and thus state preferences, is a fundamental cause of state behavior in world politics. This is the central insight of liberal international relations theory. It can be expressed colloquially in various ways: ââ¬Å"What matters most is what states want, not how they get it. â⬠ââ¬âor- ââ¬Å"Ends are more important than means. â⬠Liberal theory is distinctive in the nature of the variables it privileges. The liberal focus on variation in socially-determined state preferences distinguishes liberal theory from other theoretical traditions: realism (focusing on variation in coercive power resources), institutionalism (focusing on information), and most non-rational approaches (focusing on patterns of beliefs about appropriate means-ends relationships). In explaining patterns of war, for example, liberals do not look to inter-state imbalances of power, bargaining failure due to private information or uncertainty, or particular non-rational beliefs or propensities of individual leaders, societies, or organizations. Liberals look instead to conflicting state preferences derived from hostile nationalist or political ideologies, disputes over appropriable economic resources, or exploitation of unrepresented political constituencies. For liberals, a necessary condition for war is that social pressures lead one or more ââ¬Å"aggressorâ⬠states to possess ââ¬Å"revisionistâ⬠preferences so extreme or risk-acceptant that other states are unwilling to submit. Three specific variants of liberal theory are defined by particular types of preferences, their variation, and their impact on state behavior. Ideational liberal theories link state behavior to varied conceptions of desirable forms of cultural, political, socioeconomic order. Commercial liberal theories stress economic interdependence, including many variants of ââ¬Å"endogenous policy theory. Republican liberal theories stress the role of domestic representative institutions, elites and leadership dynamics, and executive-legislative relations. Such theories were first conceived by prescient liberals such as Immanuel Kant, Adam Smith, John Stuart Mill, John Hobson, Woodrow Wilson, and John Maynard Keynes-writing well before the deep causes (independent variables) they stress (e. g. democratization, industrialization, nationalism, and welfare provision) were widespread. This essay introduces the liberal approach in three steps. It presents two distinctive assumptions underlying and distinguishing liberal theories. Then it further explicates the three variants of liberal theory that follow from these assumptions. Finally, it reviews some distinctive strengths that liberal theories tend to share vis-a-vis other types of international relations theory. Two Unique Assumptions underlying Liberal Theory What basic assumptions underlie the liberal approach? Two assumptions liberal theory make are the assumptions of anarchy and rationality. Specifically, states (or other political actors) exist in an anarchic environment and they generally act in a broadly rational way in making decisions. 2] The anarchy assumption means that political actors exist in the distinctive environment of international politics, without a world government or any other authority with a monopoly on the legitimate use of force. They must engage in self-help. The rationality assumption means that state leaders and their domestic supporters engage in foreign policy for the instrumental purpose of securing benefits provided by (or avoiding costs imposed by) actors outside of their borders, and in making such calculations, states seek to deploy the most cost-effective means to achieve whatever their ends (preferences) may be. Liberal theory shares the first (anarchy) assumption with almost all international relations theories, and it shares the second (rationality) assumption with realism and institutionalism, but not non-rationalist process theories. Liberal theories are distinguished from other rationalist theories, such as realism and institutionalism, by two unique assumptions about world politics: (1) States represent social groups, whose views constitute state preferences; and (2) Interdependence among state preferences influences state policy. Let us consider each in turn. Assumption One: States Represent Societal Preferences The first assumption shared by liberal theories is that states represent some subset of domestic society, whose views constitute state preferences. For liberals, the state is a representative institution constantly subject to capture and recapture, construction and reconstruction, by domestic social coalitions. These social coalitions define state ââ¬Å"preferencesâ⬠in world politics at any point in time: the ââ¬Å"tastes,â⬠ââ¬Å"ends,â⬠ââ¬Å"basic interests,â⬠or ââ¬Å"fundamental social purposesâ⬠that underlie foreign policy. Political institutions constitute a critical ââ¬Å"transmission beltâ⬠by which these interests of individuals and groups in civil society enter the political realm. All individuals and groups do not wield equal influence over state policy. To the contrary, their power varies widely, depending on the context. Variation in the precise nature of representative institutions and practices helps define which groups influence the ââ¬Å"national interest. â⬠Some states may represent, ideal-typically, the preferences of a single tyrannical individual, a Pol Pot or Josef Stalin; others afford opportunities for broad democratic participation. Most lie in between. The precise preferences of social groups, weighted by their domestic power, shape the underlying goals (ââ¬Å"state preferencesâ⬠) that states pursue in world politics. Sometimes, non-governmental organizations (NGOs) and other actors may form transnational alliances to assist social forces. ââ¬Å"State-society relationsâ⬠ââ¬âthe relationship between a state and its domestic (and transnational) society in which it is embeddedââ¬âlies at the center of liberal theory. [3] Liberals believe that state preferences cannot be reduced to some simple metric or preference ordering, such as seeking ââ¬Å"securityâ⬠or ââ¬Å"wealthâ⬠. Most modern states are not Spartan: They compromise security or sovereignty in order to achieve other ends, or, indeed, just to save money. Nor do modern states uniformly seek ââ¬Å"wealth. â⬠Instead they strike rather strike complex and varied trade-offs among economic, social and political goals. Nor, finally do they seek ââ¬Å"powerâ⬠in the sense of ââ¬Å"dominationâ⬠: Many countries would clearly rather spend money on ââ¬Å"butterâ⬠rather than ââ¬Å"guns. To see how consequential the variation in goals can be, one need look no further than the implications for international relations of Germanyââ¬â¢s evolution from Adolf Hitlerââ¬â¢s preference for militant nationalism, fascist rule, autarky, and ruthless exploitation of German Lebensraum under Das Dritte Reich to the social compro mise underlying the postwar Bundesrepublik Deutschland, which favored capitalist democracy, expanding German exports, and peaceful reunification. Similarly one can look at the striking change in policy between Maoist and post-Maoist China, Soviet and post-Soviet Russia, Imperial and post-Imperial Japan, and so on. Assumption Two: Interdependence among State Preferences Influences State Behavior The second core assumption shared by liberal theories is that the interdependence among of state preferences influences state behavior. Rather than treating preferences as a fixed constant, as do realists or institutionalists, liberals seek to explain variation in preferences and its significance for world politics. The precise distribution and nature of the ââ¬Å"stakesâ⬠explains differences in state policy and behavior. States, liberals argue, orient their behavior to the precise nature of these underlying preferences: compatible or conflictual, intense or weak, and their precise scope. States require a ââ¬Å"social purposeâ⬠ââ¬â a perceived underlying stake in the matter at hand ââ¬â in order to pay any attention to international affairs, let alone to provoke conflict, inaugurate cooperation, or take any other significant foreign policy action. If there is no such interdependence among state objectives, a rational state will conduct no international relations, satisfying itself with an isolated and autarkic existence. Conflictual goals increase the incentive for of political disputes. Convergence of underlying preferences creates the preconditions for peaceful coexistence or cooperation. The critical theoretical link between state preferences, on the one hand, and state behavior, on the other, is the concept of policy interdependence. Policy interdependence refers to the distribution and interaction of preferencesââ¬âthat is, the extent to which the pursuit of state preferences necessarily imposes costs and benefits (known as policy externalities) upon other states, independent of the ââ¬Å"transaction costsâ⬠imposed by the specific strategic means chosen to obtain them. Depending on the underlying pattern of interdependence, each of the qualitative categories above, the form, substance, and depth of conflict and cooperation vary according to the precise nature and intensity of preferences. The existence of some measure of divergent fundamental beliefs, scarcity of material goods, and inequalities in domestic political power among states and social actors renders inevitable some measure of pluralism and competition among and within states. Unlike realists such as Waltz and Morgenthau, liberals do not assume these divergent interests are uniformly zero-sum. At the same time, liberals reject the utopian notion (often attributed to them by realists) of an automatic harmony of interest among individuals and groups in international society. Nor do liberals argue, as realists like Morgenthau charge, believe that each state pursues an ideal goal, oblivious of what other states do. Liberals argue instead that each state seeks to realize distinct preferences or interests under constraints imposed by the different interests of other states. [4] This distribution of preferences varies considerably. For liberals, this variationââ¬ânot realismââ¬â¢s distribution of capabilities or institutionalismââ¬â¢s distribution of informationââ¬âis of decisive causal importance in explaining state behavior. A few examples illustrate how liberal theories differ from realist, institutionalist or non-rational ones. We have already encountered the example of war in the introduction, in which liberals stress states with aggressive preferences, rather than imbalances of power, incomplete information, or non-rational beliefs and processes. Another illustration is trade policy. Economists widely agree that free trade is superior welfare-improving policy choice for states, yet trade protection is often practiced. To explain protectionism, liberals look to domestic social preferences. An important factor in almost all countries is the competitive position of affected economic sectors in global markets, which generates domestic and transnational distributional effects: Protectionism is generally backed by producers who are globally uncompetitive; free trade by producers who are globally competitive. Moreover, even if the state is a net beneficiary from free trade, domestic adjustment costs may be too high to tolerate politically, or may endanger other countervailing domestic social objectives, such as domestic social equality or environmental quality. Certain domestic political institutions, such as non-parliamentary legislative systems, which governed US trade policy before 1934, grant disproportionate power to protectionist interests. This differs from realist explanations of trade protectionism, which tend to stress the role of ââ¬Å"hegemonic powerâ⬠in structuring trade liberalization, or the need to defend self-sufficient national security within the prevailing zero-sum geopolitical competition, perhaps by maintaining self-sufficiency or by aiding allies at the expense of purely economic objectives. Institutionalists might cite the absence of appropriate international institutions, or other means to manage the complex informational tasks and collective action problemsââ¬ânegotiation, dispute resolution, enforcementââ¬ârequired to manage free trade. Those who focus on non-rational theories (psychological, cultural, organizational, epistemic, perceptual or bureaucratic) might stress an ideological disposition to accept ââ¬Å"mercantilistâ⬠theory, shared historical analogies, and the psychological predisposition to avoid losses. To further illustrate the importance of patterns of policy interdependence, consider the following three circumstances: zero-sum, harmonious and mixed preferences. In the case of zero-sum preferences, attempts by dominant social groups in one state to realize their preferences through international action may necessarily impose costs on dominant social groups in other countries. This is a case of ââ¬Å"zero-sumâ⬠preferences, similar to the ââ¬Å"realistâ⬠world. Governments face a bargaining game with few mutual gains and a high potential for interstate tension and conflict. Many ancient cities and states, including those of Ancient Athens, often imposed imperial tribute on defeated neighbors or, in extremis, killed the male population, cast women and children into slavery, and repopulated the town with their own citizensââ¬âa situation approximating zero-sum conflict. Today, it might still be argued that there are certain casesââ¬âtrade in agricultural goods by industrial democracies, for exampleââ¬âwhere entrenched national interests are so strong that no government seriously considers embracing free trade. In the case of harmonious preferences, where the externalities of unilateral olicies are optimal (or insignificant) for others, there are strong incentives for quiet coexistence with low conflict and (at most) simple forms of interstate coordination. For example, advanced industrial democracies today no longer contemplate waging war on one another, and in some areas governments have agreed to mutual recognition of certain legal standards without controversy. One case of mixed preferences is bargaining, where states can achieve common gains (or avoid common losses, as with a war) if they agree to coordinate their behavior, but may disagree strongly on the distribution of benefits or adjustment costs. Under such circumstances, one of the most important determinants of bargaining power is the intensity of the preferences of each party; the more intense their preference for a beneficial settlement, the more likely they are to make concessions (or employ coercive means) in order to achieve it. Another situation of mixed motives is a situation where interstate coordination can avoid significant risks and costs, as in agreement to avoid naval incidents at sea, or to share information on infectious diseases. In such situations, institutional pre-commitments and the provision of greater information can often improve the welfare of all parties. Liberals derive several distinctive conceptions of power, very different from that of realism. One form of international influence, for liberals, stems from the interdependence among preferences that Keohane and Nye (Power and Interdependence) call ââ¬Å"asymmetrical interdependence. â⬠All other things equal, the more interdependent a state is, the more intense its preference for a given outcome, the more power others potentially have over it; while the less a state wants something, the less a state cares about outcomes, the less intense its preferences, the less power others have over it. Situations of asymmetrical interdependence, where one state has more intense preference for an agreement than another, create bargaining power. In trade negotiations, for example, smaller and poorer countries are often more dependent on trade and thus benefit more from free trade, and thus tend to have a weaker position and make more concessions in the course of negotiations. Enlargement of the European Union is a recent instance. Relative preference intensity can also influence the outcome of war, but in a different way. Nations are in fact rarely prepared to mortgage their entire economy or military in conflict, so their power depends not on their coercive power resources, but on their resolve or will. This is why smaller states often prevail over larger ones. Vietnam, for example, did not prevail over the US in the Vietnam War because it possessed more coercive power resources, but because it had a more intense preference at stake. From Assumptions to Theories Taken by themselves, these liberal assumptionsââ¬âthe international system is anarchic, states are rational, social pressures define state preferences, interdependence among preferences dictates state behaviorââ¬âare thin. They exclude most existing realist, institutionalist, and non-rational theories, but they do not, taken by themselves, define very precisely the positive content of liberal theory. Some might rightly complain that simply pointing to state preferences opens up an unmanageably wide range of hypothetical social influences on policy. Yet, in practice, research has shown that, in practice, the range of viable liberal theories that test out empirically are relatively few, focused, and powerful. Three broad variants or categories of liberal theory exist: ideational, commercial, and republican liberalism. At the core of each lies a distinct conception of the social pressures and representative institutions that define state preferences, and the consequences for state behavior. Some of these have proven, empirically, to be among the most powerful theories in international relations. Let us consider each in turn.
Monday, January 6, 2020
People Not Ready, Request One Week - 1166 Words
In the fall, prosecutors offered him a new deal: if he pleaded guilty, heââ¬â¢d get two and a half years in prison, which meant that, with time served, he could go home soon. ââ¬Å"Ninety-nine out of a hundred would take the offer that gets you out of jail,â⬠Oââ¬â¢Meara told me. ââ¬Å"He just said, ââ¬ËNah, Iââ¬â¢m not taking it.ââ¬â¢ He didnââ¬â¢t flinch. Never talked about it. He was not taking a plea.â⬠Meanwhile, Browder kept travelling from Rikers to the Bronx courthouse and back again, shuttling between two of New York Cityââ¬â¢s most dysfunctional bureaucracies, each system exacerbating the flaws of the other. With every trip Browder made to the courthouse, another line was added to a growing stack of index cards kept in the court file: June 29, 2012: People notâ⬠¦show more contentâ⬠¦In the next twelve months, DiMango disposed of a thousand cases, some as old as five years. Judge DiMango explained to Browder, ââ¬Å"If you go to trial and lose, you could get up to fifteen.â⬠Then she offered him an even more tempting deal: plead guilty to two misdemeanorsââ¬âthe equivalent of sixteen months in jailââ¬âand go home now, on the time already served. ââ¬Å"If you want that, I will do that today,â⬠DiMango said. ââ¬Å"I could sentence you today. . . . Itââ¬â¢s up to you.â⬠ââ¬Å"Iââ¬â¢m all right,â⬠Browder said. ââ¬Å"I did not do it. Iââ¬â¢m all right.â⬠ââ¬Å"You are all right?â⬠DiMango said. ââ¬Å"Yes,â⬠he said. ââ¬Å"I want to go to trial.â⬠Back at Rikers, other prisoners were stunned. ââ¬Å"Youââ¬â¢re bugging,â⬠they told him. ââ¬Å"Youââ¬â¢re stupid. If that was me, I wouldââ¬â¢ve said I did it and went home.â⬠Browder knew that it was a gamble; even though he was innocent, he could lose at trial. ââ¬Å"I used to go to my cell and lie down and think, like, Maybe I am crazy; maybe I am going too far,â⬠he recalled. ââ¬Å"But I just did what I thought was right.â⬠On May 29th, the thirty-first court date on Browderââ¬â¢s case, there was another development. DiMango peered down from the bench. ââ¬Å"The District Attorney is really in a position right now where they cannot proceed,â⬠she said. ââ¬Å"It is their intention to dismiss the case.â⬠She explained that this could not officially happen until the next court date, which ended upShow MoreRelatedComparative Analysis Poetry Paper1179 Words à |à 5 PagesThe time and effort put into making this bird cage has great morality results for Balthazar. Being the most beautiful bird cage people in the village has ever seen, Balthazarââ¬â¢s pride and extravagant praise boosts up and he is full of confidence. Ready for delivery and payment Balthazar takes it over to the boys house and finds out the parents do not approve or such request made by their young son. Deeply devastated by the refusal of the boys parents Balthazar finds his self-pride and decides to giveRead MoreBeer Game15 21 Words à |à 7 PagesBullwhip Effect Through the numerous stages of a supply chain; key factors such as time and supply of order decisions, demand for the supply, lack of communication and disorganization can result in one of the most common problems in supply chain management.à This common problem is known as the bullwhip effect; also sometimes the whiplash effect. In this blog post we will explain this concept and outline some of the contributing factors to this issue.à [pic] TheRead MoreErik Peterson Part a and B1719 Words à |à 7 Pagesdelayed the first deadline on February 1st to begin our service. However I have submitted the revised turn-on of April 1st to headquarters. I, now with only 3 weeks left to the new deadline, have to prepare an effective plan and solve major issues in order to meet the second turn-on deadline. Moreover, I have to discuss my plan in 3 weeksââ¬â¢ time with Chip Knight, director of pre-operating system from our parent corporation, Cellular Communication Services, Inc. (CelluComm), Dashiell Harper, VP ofRead MoreEssay956 Words à |à 4 Pagesprepared, to be ready, that we find through our readings from last week and this. Last week we heard those famous lines from John, which have been recalled so many times and places where someone has been prepared to go the extra mile, to sacrifice so much for their faith, or beliefs, or for another person, as we remembered the preparedness of those during wartime who gave their lives, and freedoms and futures for ours, ââ¬Å"Greater love has no one than this: to lay down oneââ¬â¢s life for ones friendsâ⬠. Read MoreThe Treatment Of Physician Assisted Suicide1025 Words à |à 5 PagesHaving a terminally ill family member is hard because you know the days, weeks and months are numbered. Quality of life, what is that anyway? Each passing hour has the quality of life diminishing to unimaginable physical pain and anguish. Watching someone you love slip away and turn into a shell of who they once were is unbearable. This invitation is special. This special day and every precious hour will give the loved ones a time to say goodbye just before they die with dignity in physician assistedRead MoreEssay on Parentsà ´ Negligence Leads to Child Obesity863 Words à |à 4 PagesAs many people may have already noticed, child and teen obesity has become a greater problem in the United States. Could child and teen obesity be a reflection of a parentââ¬â¢s negligence? Many families donââ¬â¢t have time to cook nutritional meals, which causes many families to eat out nearly more than once a w eek. School cooked lunches arenââ¬â¢t exactly healthy either and many choices children make, parents donââ¬â¢t know about. Also, the media has a big impact on how child and teens eat. When children seeRead MoreAbortion : A Controversial Issue1256 Words à |à 6 Pagesvery controversial issue. To first start out abortion is the deliberate termination of a womanââ¬â¢s pregnancy, most often performed within the first 22 weeks of pregnancy. People can either be pro-choice or pro-life for abortion. Being pro-choice means that people believe that it is a womanââ¬â¢s choice to get an abortion if they want one. Pro-life means people believe no matter what if a woman is pregnant they should have the baby; no abortion. I intent to explain why women who get pregnant should have theRead MoreSwot Analysis : The Food Industry1465 Words à |à 6 Pagesrespectful human resource audits to search for the best way to produce positive motivation towards its employees. According to the b usiness dictionary, they explain motivation as, ââ¬Å"Internal and external factors that stimulate desire and energy in people to be continually interested and committed to a job, role or subject, or to make an effort to attain a goalâ⬠(Business Dictionary). Managers lean toward using the Human Resource Audit because their jobs consist of monitoring staff treatment, whichRead MoreMetabical: Pricing, Packaging, and Demand Forecasting for a New Weight-Loss Drug636 Words à |à 3 Pagesweight-loss drugs were approved forà use in both obese (BMI gt;30) and severely obese (BMIgt;40) individuals. à Metabical is a dual-layer formulation: the first layer contained an appetite suppressant and the second one a fat blocker and calorie absorption agent meditonan. à It helped people to lose weight, but also, it helped with behavior modification and healthier eating habits. à 2)à à à à à Printup (the protagonist) suggested various methods for forecasting demand.à What are the strengths and weaknessesRead MoreCambridge Sciences Pharmaceuticals ( Csp ) Essay1720 Words à |à 7 Pagesactively trying to lose weight, and 15 percent are comfortable using prescription drugs to help reach their weight-loss goals. Out of these respondents, 12 percent said they would immediately make an appointment with their health care provider and request a prescription. The ideal Metabical consumer was determined by Printup and found to be overweight college-educated females ages 35 to 65. To see how potential customers would respond to Metabical, Printup decided to project demand using three approaches
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)